Illustration

 

 

Erich Landsteiner / Tim Soens (Eds.)

Farming the City

Jahrbuch für Geschichte des ländlichen Raumes/Rural History Yearbook (JGLR/RHY)

Herausgeberinnen und Herausgeber:

Georg Fertig (Halle), Dietlind Hüchtker (Leipzig/Halle), Martin Knoll (Salzburg), Fridolin Krausmann (Wien), Erich Landsteiner (Wien), Ernst Langthaler (Linz/St. Pölten), Margareth Lanzinger (Wien), Peter Moser (Bern), Markus Schermer (Innsbruck), Verena Winiwarter (Wien)

Geschäftsführender Herausgeber:

Ernst Langthaler

Herausgeber dieses Bandes:

Erich Landsteiner und Tim Soens

Redaktion dieses Bandes:

Martin Bauer, Brigitte Semanek und Thomas Stockinger unter Mitarbeit von Markus Rheindorf und Ulrich Schwarz-Gräber

Wissenschaftlicher Beirat:

Juri Auderset (Bern), Arnd Bauerkämper (Berlin), Markus Cerman † (Wien), Geoff Cunfer (Saskatoon), Andreas Dix (Bamberg), Werner Drobesch (Klagenfurt), Ulrich Ermann (Graz), Christine Fertig (Münster), Deborah Fitzgerald (Cambridge, MA), Gesine Gerhard (Des Moines, IA), Sandro Guzzi (Lausanne), Ernst Hanisch (Salzburg), Reinhard Johler (Tübingen), Karl Kaser (Graz), Michael Kopsidis (Halle), Markus Krzoska (Gießen), Markus Lampe (Wien), Michael Limberger (Gent), Jon Mathieu (Luzern), Wolfgang Meixner (Innsbruck), Michael Mitterauer (Wien), David Moon (York), Norbert Ortmayr (Salzburg), Marianne Penker (Wien), Ulrich Pfister (Münster), David Sabean (Los Angeles), Roman Sandgruber (Linz), Gloria Sanz Lafuente (Pamplona), Brigitta Schmidt-Lauber (Wien), Leonore Scholtze-Irrlitz (Berlin), Anton Schuurman (Wageningen), Stefan Sonderegger (Zürich), Elisabeth Timm (Münster), Oswald Überegger (Bozen), Nadine Vivier (Le Mans), Paul Warde (Cambridge), Norbert Weigl (Wien), Clemens Zimmermann (Saarbrücken)

Illustration

Erich Landsteiner / Tim Soens (Eds.)

Farming the City

The Resilience and Decline of Urban Agriculture in European History

Resilienz und Niedergang der städtischen Landwirtschaft in der europäischen Geschichte

Jahrbuch für Geschichte des ländlichen Raumes/Rural History Yearbook 2019

Illustration

Table of Contents

Special Issue: Farming the City

Erich Landsteiner/Tim Soens
Editorial: Farming the City

Tim Soens
Urban Agriculture and Urban Food Provisioning in Pre-1850 Europe: Towards a Research Agenda

Roberto Leggero/Mirella Montanari
Two Experiences of Urban Agriculture in Medieval Piedmont.
A Comparison of Chieri and Novara (Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries)

Henry R. French
“… a great hurt to many, and of advantage to very few“.
Urban Comon Lands, Civic Government, and the Problem of Resource Management in English Towns, 1500–1840

Piotr Miodunka
The Longue Durée in Polish Towns: Agriculture from the Sixteenth to the Nineteenth Century

Pieter De Graef/Wouter Ronsijn
From Home Food Production to Professional Farming. The Social and Geographical Continuum of Urban Agriculture: Nineteenth-century Oudenaarde and Kortrijk, Belgium

Ines Peper
Between Village, Utopian Settlement, and Garden City: Urban Agriculture in the Company Housing Project of Eisenheim (Founded in 1844) in Historical Context

Åsa Ahrland
Fields, Meadows, and Gardens – an Integral Part of the City. The Example of Södermalm in Stockholm, Sweden

Erich Landsteiner
Urban Viticulture in Late Medieval and Early Modern Central Europe

Johannes Koder
Landwirtschaft beiderseits der Stadtmauern. Konstantinopels Versorgung mit Gemüse aufgrund der Geoponika

Articles

Carine Pachoud/Markus Schermer
Reconciling Tradition and Innovation in Traditional Mountain Cheese Value Chains: The Role of Social Capital. The Case of the Artisanal Serrano Cheese Value Chain in Southern Brazil

Erich Landsteiner / Tim Soens

Editorial: Farming the City

At the beginning of the twenty-first century, urban agriculture is rapidly gaining importance.1 All over the world, urban dwellers gather to cultivate crops and vegetables or to raise some poultry or pigs, often on a cooperative basis and on small plots of ‘marginal’ land. In an urban world characterised by globalising food markets and social polarisation – but also by increasing food insecurity –, citizens practice urban agriculture in a combined effort to diversify their food supplies, shorten the food chain and strengthen community life. Urban agriculture today is a highly diversified and multi-layered phenomenon, and its roots are both very old and very recent. Throughout European history it has appeared in different forms and guises. In some parts of Europe, urban agriculture seems to have declined at an early stage, whereas in others food production remained part and parcel of the urban economy until very recently, both as a component of a diversified household economy and in a highly specialised and professionalised form (for instance as horticulture or viticulture). Today, this urban agricultural heritage might offer inspiration to those who are looking for low-tech alternatives to high-precision and energy-intensive variants of urban agriculture like so-called vertical farms.2

It has already been noted that in most current discussions urban agriculture is treated as a new phenomenon and that this might have to do with its neglect in the prevailing historiography on towns and urbanisation.3 Due to a long tradition, going back to the nineteenth century, of defining towns as “big non-agrarian settlements”,4 historians are indeed ill equipped to tackle the new challenge of providing a historical background to this societal demand and the initiatives connected with it. Whatever else is marshalled in the numerous attempts to define a town and urbanity in European (or Western) historiography, especially when they are concerned with medieval origins, the functional difference between town and country is generally stressed.5 The other criterion, intimately connected with the functional definition, is demographic and relies on a – unavoidably arbitrary – threshold of the number of inhabitants, usually set at 5,000 or 10,000 people.6

This functional cum demographic separation of town and country is, in both respects, a “deceptively simple dichotomy”.7 From the functional perspective, it necessarily neglects the involvement of towns, both large and small, in agriculture as well as the production and processing of agricultural goods and commodities by their inhabitants in the European past; from the demographic perspective it neglects the fact that a significant proportion of premodern European towns fell below the applied thresholds, relegating large parts of Europe to the status of non-urbanisation until the nineteenth century. This has not gone unnoticed. In his introduction to a volume on Small Towns in Early Modern Europe, Peter Clark stated:

“Throughout the medieval and early modern period the small town, with a few hundred or thousand people, often clustered behind stone or earthen ramparts, with farms and orchards in its midst, and a handful of public buildings around the marketplace, was a constant and quintessential feature of the European landscape. […] Across Europe, there were five or more times as many small towns as all other kinds of urban community put together.”8

Nevertheless, the functional and/or demographic definition of towns and urbanity continues to dominate the more synthetic accounts of the past constitutions of European towns and of economic development in general. It is, for example, widely used to estimate changes in agricultural productivity by breaking down populations into urban, rural agricultural and rural non-agricultural, and then applying the urban ratios thus established to measure agricultural labour productivity over space and time.9 It is highly significant that research on proto-industrial production has led to the differentiation of the rural population into agricultural and non-agricultural sections, whereas the urban population (identified by applying the usual size thresholds) is always – with some caveats of low significance – considered to be non-agricultural.10 For the moment, it can only be surmised how the results of this kind of measurement would change if we lowered the demographic threshold to include the other four fifths of (small) towns into the urban ratio and split the urban population into agricultural and non-agricultural. Needless to say, this would be as arbitrary as splitting the rural population into these categories, considering the frequent combination of agrarian and non-agrarian occupations in town and countryside. It would certainly raise – perhaps even double – absolute urban ratios, especially for those regions where most towns were below the size threshold usually applied, but would it also change their relative standing with respect to more urbanised regions? Conversely, we could also ask to what extent the consideration of the weight of agricultural activities in the now more numerous towns would change the gaps in the estimates of regional agricultural productivity. It is far from clear that these sample changes would counterbalance and leave the results unchanged.11

Was the presence of agrarian occupations in towns simply a matter of size? Given the fact that a town of 10,000 inhabitants required about 9,000 hectares to secure its supply of bread grains in a preindustrial environment, there must have been limits of size to the self-sufficiency of towns in terms of food provisioning. Climbing up the size scale of towns, the interplay between urban food production and food markets tipped clearly in favour of the market.12 However, we should, on the one hand, not underestimate the capacity of towns to cater for themselves given they had sufficient access to arable land. For a sample of twelve Swedish towns in the size bracket between 500 and 5,000 inhabitants, it has recently been calculated that their majority would, in theory, have been able to produce between 50 per cent and 100 per cent of the grain consumed in the respective town, up to and into the nineteenth century.13 On the other hand, urban agriculture was – in many instances, also including small towns – not limited to food production by and for the townspeople, but rather dedicated to highly commercialised branches of agriculture.

Was the presence and extent of urban agriculture a matter of location? In the context of the overarching and evolving division of labour within Europe, the size, growth potential and functional specialisation of towns in manufacture and trade clearly declined from the centre to the periphery. The economic constitution of the many Mediterranean, east-central European and Scandinavian agro-towns would then reflect the higher concentration and higher development of industry and merchant capital in the centre(s), and urban development and underdevelopment (if one associates the weight of agrarian production in towns with the latter) would constitute the opposite sides of the same coin. This conclusion has been stressed for some time in research on centre-periphery relations and certainly has merit, as long as one does not conflate urban agriculture with self-sufficient subsistence production and takes into consideration its often high degree of specialisation and commercialisation.14 But even before the core of European urbanisation moved from southern to north-western Europe during the seventeenth century, in most Mediterranean towns, both large and small, the landownership of citizens and agricultural production for the household and the market constituted an important sector of the urban economy.15

Finally, we could ask if the relationship of towns and agricultural production is a matter of the type of farming and land use. Although the involvement of towns in agrarian production spanned a wide spectrum from small-scale food production for subsistence over market gardening to fully developed commercial farming, there seems to have existed an urban preference for market-oriented branches of agrarian production such as viticulture, hops and tobacco growing, cattle-raising, and the processing of agrarian raw materials oriented towards regional and supra-regional markets (wine making and beer brewing, the processing of dye-plants), often in close interaction with and based on the institutionalised coercive power of towns over the surrounding countryside.

In order to understand the organisation, resilience and failure of urban agriculture – broadly defined as all forms of food production in an urban context involving urban citizens as producers – this issue of the Rural History Yearbook aims to develop a comparative and long-term approach, with a particular focus on the actors involved in urban agriculture, their income strategies, and the social and economic configurations in which they operate. Most contributions to this special issue resulted from a double session at the 2017 Rural History Conference in Leuven (Belgium), organised by the Comparative Rural History Network (CORN). In this session and the special issue, the contributors were asked to reflect upon the drivers and actors explaining the long-term continuity of urban agriculture in some contexts and its rapid demise in others.

In his introductory article, Tim Soens elaborates a conceptual and methodological framework for the study of urban agriculture in the past, emphasising the role of demography, property rights, the organisation of the household economy, the commercialisation and specialisation of the ‘agrarian’ economy in the urban hinterland, the institutional framework and, finally, the role of crises (famine, warfare) disrupting normal food chains. Roberto Leggero and Mirella Montanari identify two different forms of development and resilience of urban agrarian production in northern Italy during the communal age by comparing the Piedmont cities of Chieri and Novara. Both cities had spaces of agricultural use within their walls and intensely regulated peri-urban agriculture, but developed specific relationships with their wider rural environment due to different ecological settings. Chieri, situated in a dry hill area, colonised her contado by planting vines and establishing small farm units cultivated by sharecroppers. Novara, on the plain traversed by the river Ticino, specialised in raising cattle on irrigated meadows. Henry French reminds us that towns, in his case 170 English towns, often possessed extensive commons. He explores the relationship between the agrarian and political governance of these urban common lands in the early modern period by pondering Elinor Ostrom’s “Common Pool Resource” model against approaches stressing the unequal distribution of power within urban communities. French concludes that the longevity and eventual abolition of urban commons in England involved the assertion of the access rights of a privileged minority in the towns and its challenge by reforms designed to redistribute power through the expansion of corporate electorates.

Piotr Miodunka’s paper addresses the agrarian features of the many small towns of southwestern Poland, where agriculture was the primary source of income for the majority of inhabitants until the late nineteenth century. Drawing on the cadastral survey established by the government of Austrian Galicia in the 1780s, he analyses to what extent these towns were self-sufficient in their grain supply. Pieter De Graef and Wouter Ronsijn explore the entire spectrum of urban agriculture in the Flemish towns of Oudendaarde and Kortrijk in the nineteenth century through a micro-level approach using data on households from agricultural censuses, population registers and tax lists. In contrast to the situation in Polish towns, only about 10 per cent of the population of the much larger Flemish towns had access to agricultural land, which was very unequally distributed. The social continuum from home food growers to professional gardeners and farmers overlapped with a geographical continuum from urban core to rural fringe, stretching from small garden plots cultivated by self-provisioning households to produce vegetables and potatoes in the city centres to farms producing cereals and other crops as well as holdings of professional gardeners on the outskirts of the towns.

Ines Peper investigates the establishment and constitution of the mining company settlement Eisenheim in Germany’s Ruhr district, where housing and access to land were provided by the company to attract and bind workers as well as to supplement their wages. She places this model of transition between traditional village and proletarian urban district within the context of similar projects, such as the settlements of the Moravian Church community in Herrnhut and other places, and the garden allotment initiatives and garden city projects in nineteenth century German towns, considering them as forerunners of many current projects of urban gardening. Åsa Ahrland presents a long-term perspective on the urban development of Södermalm island in Stockholm. In the course of the expansion of the Swedish capital, the island was transformed from an agrarian supply zone first into a gardening zone, where vegetables and tobacco were cultivated, then into an industrial district with a large working class population and allotment gardens, until it underwent gentrification at the turn to the twenty-first century. She identifies the establishment of the modern Swedish welfare state as the key to understanding why urban agriculture disappeared in Södermalm.

In Erich Landsteiner’s paper, vine-growing and wine production are discussed as specific forms of urban agriculture in late medieval and early modern (central) Europe. Refuting the implications of the concept of Ackerbürgerstadt, he investigates the economic and social characteristics of vine-growing towns by drawing on the examples of Vienna and Retz, a small town in Lower Austria, stressing the high degree of social differentiation, the endemic class-struggles between bourgeois vineyard owners and wage labourers, and the regulation of the wine market by the town authorities. Johannes Koder’s contribution on the provisioning of Constantinople with vegetables mirrored in the Geoponica is the only paper not presented in the session at the 2017 Rural History Conference in Leuven. It is included here as a very welcome extension of the geographical and chronological scope of this collection.

In the section for papers beyond the scope of the thematic issue, which we introduced only recently with the 2019 issue of the Yearbook, Carine Pachoud and Markus Schermer present a case study of the artisanal Serrano cheese value chain in Southern Brazil. The authors analyse strategies for building a resilient value chain by studying the role of social capital in the balance between maintaining traditions and the emergence of territorial innovations. Serrano cheese is produced by beef cattle farmers in the Campos de Cima da Serra region in the Brazilian states of Rio Grande do Sul and Santa Catarina. Pachoud and Schermer explore the historical development of cheese production in this area in relation to findings from their interviews with local actors conducted in 2017 and 2018. They observe that the recent creation of producers’ associations which connect different actors through linking and bridging social capital was vital for territorial innovation to emerge. This study offers new perspectives on traditional food value chains in rural mountain areas that are often excluded from current discussions on globalised and production-oriented agriculture.

As editors of this special issue, we finally want to thank both the editorial board of the Rural History Yearbook and the peer reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions, as well as the Comparative Rural History Network (CORN) for their support.

 

____________

Erich Landsteiner, University of Vienna, Department of Economic and Social History, Universitätsring 1, 1010 Vienna, Austria, erich.landsteiner@univie.ac.at; Tim Soens, Universiteit Antwerpen, Centre for Urban History, Stadscampus, Sint-Jacobsmarkt 13, S.SJ.306, 2000 Antwerpen, Belgium, tim.soens@uantwerpen.be

1 This is also mirrored by research networks such as the COST (European Cooperation in Science and Technology) Action TD 1106 Urban Agriculture Europe (2012–2016), which has produced the “Barcelona Declaration on Urban Agriculture and the Common Agricultural Policy”. See Frank Lohrberg et al. (eds.), Urban Agriculture Europe, Berlin 2015, and http://www.urban-agriculture-europe.org/files/130624_barcelona_declaration_on_urban_agriculture.pdf (last visited 2 Feb. 2020). On the global scale, the “Milan Urban Food Policy Pact and Framework for Action”, launched in 2015 by FAO and signed by 167 cities from 63 countries, is a major initiative in this context. See Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (ed.), The Role of Cities in the Transformation of Food Systems: Sharing Lessons from Milan Pact Cities, Rome 2018, http://www.milanurbanfoodpolicypact.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/10/CA0912EN.pdf (last visited 2 Feb. 2020).

2 See, for instance, the recent Herrenhausen Conference in Hannover on Urban Agricultural Heritage and the Shaping of Future Cities, 6–8 May 2019. A conference report is available under: http://www.ua-heritage.com/wp-content/uploads/2019/08/Conference-Summary_Urban-Agricultural-Heritage.pdf (last visited 2 Feb. 2020).

3 Ruth Glasser, The Farm in the City in the Recent Past: Thoughts on a More Inclusive Urban Historiography, in: Journal of Urban History 44/3 (2018), 501–518.

4 See, for a recent example of this approach to defining a ‘town’, Ferdinand Opll, Das Werden der mittelalterlichen Stadt, in: Historische Zeitschrift 280 (2005), 561–589, 564.

5 To cite only two prominent authors: Henri Pirenne, Medieval Cities. Their Origins and the Revival of Trade, 3rd revised printing, Princeton 1939, 212: “If we wished […] to sum up its essential points in one phrase, perhaps it would be possible to say that the city of the Middle Ages […] was a commercial and industrial commune living in the shelter of a fortified enclosure and enjoying a law, an administration and a jurisprudence of exception which made it a collective, privileged personality.” Susan Reynolds, English Towns in a European Context, in: Jörg Jarnut/Peter Johanek (eds.), Die Frühgeschichte der europäischen Stadt im 11. Jahrhundert (Städteforschung A 43), Köln/Weimar/Wien 1998, 207–218, 208: “My definition […] has two parts. The first part is functional: a town is a permanent and concentrated human settlement in which a significant proportion of the population is engaged in non-agricultural occupations […]. A town therefore normally lives, at least partly, off food produced by people who live outside it.” Reynold’s second criterion is the identity and the self-perception of the inhabitants of town and countryside. See also her study Kingdoms and Communities in Western Europe, 900–1300, 2nd ed., Oxford 1997, 155–158. A thoughtful discussion of the advantages and drawbacks of a purely functional definition is found in Stephan R. Epstein, Introduction. Town and Country in Europe, 1300–1800, in: idem (ed.), Town and Country in Europe, 1300–1800, Cambridge 2011, 1–29.

6 Jan de Vries, European Urbanization, 1500–1800, London 1984, after opting for a functional definition, set the threshold “for separating urban from rural places” at 10,000 inhabitants and is convinced that, “so long as the threshold level used for one of these criteria, population, is as high as 10,000 the others hardly need to be examined” (53). His other criteria are “population densities, percentages of the workforce in non-agricultural occupations and a measure of diversity in the occupational structure” (22).

7 Epstein, Introduction, 1.

8 Peter Clark, Introduction, in: idem (ed.), Small Towns in Early Modern Europe, Cambridge 1995, 1–21, 1; see also Epstein, Introduction, 1–2.

9 This method, originally devised by E. A. Wrigley, Urban Growth and Agricultural Change: England and the Continent in the Early Modern Period, in: Journal of Interdisciplinary History 15/4 (1985), 683–728, is further developed by Robert C. Allen, Economic Structure and Agricultural Productivity in Europe, 1300–1800, in: European Review of Economic History 3 (2000), 1–25.

10 See, for example, Allen, Economic Structure, 4: “Clearly, some people lived in small cities and cultivated the surrounding fields or grazed stock on meadows and commons. There is no easy way to estimate the number of urban farmers, but their number was small as is the error from assuming it was zero.”

11 See Epstein, Introduction, 3 and 9, for a ponderation of similar questions.

12 See, for that matter, the contribution by Tim Soens in this volume.

13 Annika Björklund, Historical Urban Agriculture. Food Production and Access to Land in Swedish Towns before 1900 (Acta Universitatis Stockholmiensis 20), Stockholm 2010, 103–153, 135. See also the discussion of this matter for towns in Lesser Poland by Piotr Miodunka in this volume.

14 For east-central Europe, see Maria Bogucka, The Towns of East-Central Europe from the Fourteenth to the Seventeenth Century, in: Antoni Maczak/Henryk Samsonowicz/Peter Burke (eds.), East-Central Europe in Transition. From the Fourteenth to the Seventeenth Century, Cambridge/Paris 1985, 97–108; Vera Bácskai, Small Towns in Eastern Central Europe, in: Clark (ed.), Small Towns, 77–89, and Jaroslaw Miller, Urban Societies in East-Central Europe, 1500–1700, Aldershot 2008, 197–235. For southern Europe, see Juan E. Gelabert, Cities, Towns and Small Towns in Castile, 1500–1800, in: Clark, Small Towns, 271–294, and Daniel Curtis, Is There an ‘Agro-town’ Model for Southern Italy? Exploring the Diverse Roots and Development of the Agro-town Structure through a Comparative Case Study in Apulia, in: Continuity and Change 28/3 (2013), 377–419.

15 Corrado Vivanti, Città e campagne, in: Ruggiero Romano (ed.), Storia dell’economia italiana, vol. 2: L’etá moderna: verso la crisi, Torino 1991, 243–283.

Tim Soens

Urban Agriculture and Urban Food Provisioning in Pre-1850 Europe: Towards a Research Agenda

Abstract: “Feeding the city” has been a prominent topic in historical literature for many decades. Most of this literature, however, remained based on the assumption that cities above a certain population level are essentially fed through the market, with rural agricultural surpluses being exchanged for the products of urban industry and trade. Stimulated by recent articulations of alternative ways of urban food provisioning, this article reconsiders the importance of urban agriculture in European towns before 1850 from the perspective of “urban food alternatives”. The scattered evidence suggests that in many European towns a significant part of the urban population was directly involved in food production, but also that important differences persisted both between towns and between households in a town. While traditional interpretations – for instance, those linking urban agriculture with small towns, poverty, or the rise of commercial horticulture – fail to explain this spatial, social, and temporal variation, a better understanding of the success and decline of urban agriculture in different market configurations and in different social contexts might offer an important historical contribution to present-day debates on the viability and social dynamics of such urban food alternatives.

Key Words: urban agriculture, urban food supplies, horticulture, market gardening, famine

Introduction: reconsidering urban food provisioning in the past

How to feed a premodern city? For Henri Pirenne, founding father of European medieval history, the answer was quite simple: cities were based on industry and commerce, while food was produced in the countryside.1 Hence city-dwellers were obliged to convert part of their income into food, for which they had a wide variety of markets and shops at their disposal. Six centuries before Pirenne, Ambrogio Lorenzetti, painter of the famous Buon Governo fresco in the Palazzo Pubblico of Siena, presented us with a similar picture of a bucolic, though hardworking, contado supplying the urban shops and markets with a perpetual flow of food. In neighboring Florence this was estimated to be 4,000 oxen, 60,000 sheep, 20,000 goats, 30,000 pigs, 25 million quarters of wine and 474,500 bushels of grain per year for a pre-Black Death population of about 110,000 inhabitants.2 And yet a small detail in the cityscape of Lorenzetti’s Buon Governo fresco reminds us that urban food supply might be more complex than the straightforward case of rural supply meeting urban demand at the market: within the city walls a man is herding a small herd of goats. Does the tiny scene represent the delivery of fresh meat from the surrounding countryside to the urban butchers? Possibly. However, the goats are clearly being guided towards the city wall, not the urban market. The goats remind us of the importance of animal life within the medieval city, as witnessed by their appearance in countless urban regulations and, increasingly, restrictions in an ever more complicated urban “environmental law”.3 One of the key goals of such regulation was precisely to manage the access to alternative forms of food supply that parts of the urban population enjoyed, thereby bypassing the market. Apart from animal husbandry, urban households might engage in horticulture, wine-growing, or even cereal cultivation. Also, these foods might be supplied by tenants or sharecroppers working a piece of land they owned in the countryside – in a city like Siena in the fourteenth century, urban households, and not just those of the elite, owned massive amounts of land in their contado.4 In addition they might benefit from occasional or regular gifts of food distributed by charitable foundations, elite families supporting their retinue, confraternities sharing a meal, or close relatives making a testamentary bequest.

When focusing on the level of households, the history of urban food supply might be much more complex than food history allows us to believe. Since Fernand Braudel and other historians working in the tradition of the French Annales school started to investigate the material conditions of urban life in the 1960s, urban food supply automatically became a central issue in historiography. In an environment which was inspired by both Malthusian and Marxist models, food was about calories and class. It was considered in terms of access to staple foods like grain, beer, wine, and the like, which had to ensure the subsistence of the average city-dweller.5 Feeding the city hence seemed above all a question of acquiring sufficient quantities of grain – and to a lesser extent, meat – and assuring that there were enough foodstuffs available even during difficult times such as those of harvest failure or war. Since Braudel, numerous studies have been published about the food supply of individual cities before 1800, in addition to the organisation of comparative roundtables.6

Scholarship has usually distinguished between two basic strategies enabling such a massive transfer of food from the countryside to the hungry city: coercion (usually the coercive power of the “state”) and the market. In European history, the importance of providing food to cities through coercion probably had its heyday in the annonae politics of the Roman Empire, when free grain distribution had to feed – and appease – the imperial capitals of Rome and, later, Constantinople.7 Moreover, it was also a strong defining feature of the privileged position of Paris in the grain policies of Early Modern France8 and in the close link between food supply and territorial expansion in Renaissance Venice.9 On the other hand, the standard example of market-driven food provisioning is provided by the strategies of medieval London before 1300, as elaborated in the very influential “Feeding the City” project. Elaborating on von Thünen’s model of concentric land use surrounding the “isolated city”, Bruce Campbell, Derek Keene, and others were able to demonstrate how growing urban demand induced a gradual intensification of land use in an expanding hinterland, with supply and demand being matched through a relatively “open” market which included multiple buyers and sellers.10 Research on other premodern cities arrived at similar results.11 The demand-driven logic of the “Feeding the City” model was underpinned by the work of urban geographers explaining the gradual demise of food production near the built environment of the city: in a context of urban growth, higher bid-rents for residential and industrial land use inevitably pushed out agricultural and horticultural activities.12 Explaining evolutions in urban food supply thus requires economic historians to be attentive both to the development of the coercive power of cities and their rulers, and to patterns of population densities and market integration.13

The dichotomy between a food-producing countryside and a food-consuming city is even more prominent in recent literature on “urban metabolism”, which aims to map the continuous flows of energy, food, and raw materials imported from the hinterland and needed to sustain urban “life”. Existing work on the urban food metabolism is based on two binary pairs of almost antagonistic categories: “town” and “hinterland”, “consumption” and “production” – the so-called “metabolic rift”.14 Hence, metabolic thinking is intimately linked to commodification: food and other resources are processed as commodities and traded through or from the city.15 From a metabolic view, urban growth is conceived as an expanding wave gradually encroaching upon low-productive land and transforming its natural resources into commodities transported to an ever-hungry city.16

On the other hand, the awareness that urban food supply may work very differently from one household to another has been an essential feature of famine history over the past three decades. Inspired by the work of Nobel Prize winner Amartya Sen, famine history saw an important shift away from the aggregate level of cities or regions to the level of individual households.17 According to Sen, food shortage was usually not induced by insufficient food availability in society as a whole, but rather by the insufficient “entitlements” to food enjoyed by some groups and individuals within a given society. Entitlement, conceived by Sen as “the ability of people to command food through the legal means available in that society”, is a powerful concept capable of embracing all kinds of access to food. These include food production on one’s own land, the “endowment”, which produces “direct entitlements”; the conversion of labour and capital into food via the market, referred to as “exchange entitlements”; as well as other legal rights to food mobilised through distributions, gifts, or solidarities. While the concept of entitlement provides us with an ideal analytical tool for grasping the multiplicity of paths of food supply at the household level, most entitlement scholars, including Amartya Sen himself, were primarily interested in the role of the market as an – imperfect – allocator of food in times of famine.18 Direct entitlements as well as entitlements via other legal rights have received only scant attention.

But what about Lorenzetti’s goats, then? Is it possible that historians have dramatically underestimated the importance of such alternative entitlements to food provisioning in cities? Food studies of present-day cities increasingly point to the myriad ways in which urban households experiment with alternative ways of providing for food, outside regular market arrangements and outside direct involvement of the public authorities. Consumers themselves are producing food in all kinds of urban and peri-urban agriculture (UPA) – from rooftop gardens via guerrilla gardening to community farms.19 They are also exploring other “alternative food networks” by buying food on farmers’ markets or engaging in community-supported agriculture, or they acquire access to food through a new kind of “sharing economy”.20 While the motivations behind these practices are highly variable and the notion of “market independence” is often questionable,21 they all challenge mainstream food systems based on traditional agro-industry and on the anonymous globalised food distribution chains.22

Given the potential multiplicity of sources of food supply at the level of individual urban households, historians too have to question the self-evidence of markets and/or states as allocators of food. For pre-industrial cities, scattered literature already suggests the importance of urban gardens,23 the presence of rural “food farms” directly supplying elite households,24 and the importance of food gifts.25 However, because of the lack of systematic research on food strategies at the household level (and not only for urban upper-class households), it remains difficult to explain why such alternative ways of food provisioning disappeared in particular contexts while they persisted and grew in others. Based on the available, and highly fragmented, literature, the rest of this contribution hence offers a very preliminary survey of the changing importance of such alternative sources of urban food supply in European history before 1850, with particular emphasis on the role of UPA.

Mapping the variety and significance of urban agriculture in European history

In the preceding section, we argued that historians should broaden their analysis of urban food supply to include all kinds of alternative food supply chains. The direct production of food through forms of urban agriculture – and urban husbandry – constitutes an important aspect of such alternative urban food supply, although the two are not synonymous. While alternative food supply can include food produced by rural producers, urban agriculture – defined here as food production by urban dwellers – can also be firmly embedded in market arrangements.

Mapping the variety and significance of urban agriculture in the past, however, is far from easy, just as it is today,26 given that many activities take place in the private sphere, out of sight of official registration and taxation. Generally speaking, the available literature tends to distinguish three contexts in which urban agriculture flourished. First of all, few historians will doubt the importance of agricultural activities in the many small towns which constituted the backbone of the European urban network before 1850. In a small town like Colchester in England, two thirds of all taxpayers in 1301 were involved in some form of food production.27 Rodney Hilton saw a figure of 2,000 inhabitants as the threshold in distinguishing between town and countryside.28 Such small towns, or Ackerbürgerstädte as they are labelled in German literature, can even be considered an integral part of medieval peasant society.29 And although most urban and even rural historians would argue that involvement in food production did not necessarily diminish the industrial or commercial essence of such small towns, nor their urbanity in regard to culture, legal status, or identity,30 access to food that was unmediated by the market is by and large considered as incompatible with urban growth, or as Peter Clark has argued: “accelerating urbanization was only made possible by increasing agrarian imports from urban hinterlands and the growth of […] markets”.31

Secondly, alternative urban food entitlements are often associated with contexts of poverty and crisis. For nineteenth-century municipalities and charitable organisations, the promotion of allotment gardening proved an ideal instrument for improving subsistence levels without having to raise wages, while at the same time “protecting” workers from subversive socialist influences.32 During both World Wars, bare necessity drove urban households to direct food production on a massive scale.33 In the pre-industrial period as well, the persistence of food production by urban households might be associated with the typical makeshift economy of the urban poor: one pig, some poultry, and some home-grown vegetables might foster survival in uncertain times.

And thirdly, on the opposite face of the same coin, we find the rise of commercial horticulture – the specialised cultivation of fresh products such as vegetables or dairy – for the urban market, typically found in the inner circle of a von Thünen model. In different parts of northwestern Europe, horticultural activities apparently experienced a tendency towards professionalisation in the Early Modern period. English historians even speak of a horticultural “revolution” from the late sixteenth century onwards, which tends to be associated with Dutch immigrants fleeing the horror of religious persecution during the Eighty Years’ War.34 Near London in particular, some districts saw a proliferation of horticultural activities providing the growing city with an increasingly diverse supply of vegetables such as melons, asparagus, cucumbers, and so forth, produced by professional horticulturalists who continuously refined their production techniques throughout the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, from glass bells to hotbeds. In 1718 the post-mortem inventory of one Robert Gascoine listed no fewer than 1,240 bellglasses in three gardens.35 For Paris, a recent study by Gurvil revealed a similar tendency towards professionalisation in a somewhat earlier period. Whereas fifteenth-century Paris was still home to quite a few proper farmers (laboureurs) practicing a rather mainstream agriculture, sometimes even within the city walls, in the sixteenth century the laboureurs gave way to jardiniers, organised in a guild.36 While most of the gardens were situated at the outskirts of the city or in the banlieue, each new extension of the city walls paradoxically entailed an increase in the amount of gardens and fields intra muros. At the same time some professional gardening areas persisted at a short distance from the city centre – such as the Couture du Temple, which from the fifteenth to the seventeenth century transformed from a cereal field into a gardening space and then into a residential quarter.37

Mediterranean Europe had a much older tradition of urban horticulture, often concentrated in irrigated areas of intensive cultivation near the city. Like many Iberian towns, Valencia had an important irrigated zone of intensive agriculture and horticulture in its immediate neighborhood: the hortas or huertas, which built on elaborate irrigation structures pre-dating the Christian conquest.38 In the later Middle Ages, agriculture in the hortas was based on intensive smallholding farms which increasingly incorporated commercial cash crops like sugarcane and mulberry trees.39 Even though parts of the horta laid outside direct urban jurisdiction, it was profoundly urban in terms of how it was regulated (the guardia de l’horta), in terms of landownership (parts of it belonged to the city-based nobility), and in terms of its labourers, who were recruited among city-dwellers. Finally, apart from horticulture we should not underestimate the importance of dairy production within or near the city walls. Milk was one of the most difficult food products to transport over long distances. As a consequence, even mid-nineteenth-century London, at that time the largest city in Europe, saw 80 percent of its milk consumption still produced in the immediate vicinity of the city.40

Over the past years, however, new research has increasingly shown that many instances of urban agriculture do not fit into any of these categories. First of all, urban food production by non-professional producers (“home food gardens”) was not limited to small cities or Ackerbürgerstädte. In Rennes in the 1450s, 43.5 to 59 percent of the houses in the medieval parts and still 17 percent of the houses in the densely built Roman town centre had a vegetable garden or potager.41 Fifteenth-century Rennes, the capital of the independent duchy of Brittany, was a medium-sized city of about 12,000 inhabitants. In his study of medieval Toulouse, which numbered 20,000 to 30,000 residents, Philipp Wolff also noted that only a few urban households were not self-sufficient in both grain and wine – although their fields and vineyards were not necessarily situated in the immediate vicinity of the town.42 Geoarchaeological research also provides compelling new evidence for the importance and persistence of urban food production in both smaller and larger towns.43

Secondly, in some contexts home food gardens may have been more important for the middling and upper layers of society than for their poorer neighbours. Control over food supply was an important asset in a premodern society and hence an excellent social indicator. In the Catalan city of Manresa, most households disposed of food stocks exceeding 100 daily rations. The 20 percent poorest households, however, did not possess such food stocks, and hence were more dependent on daily market purchases than their wealthier neighbours.44 In a late medieval Mediterranean context, drinking one’s own wine was a matter of status: Francesco di Marco Datini, the famous fourteenth-century merchant of Prato, produced a wine befitting “great gentlemen” and used it as a gift within his extended commercial network.45 However, it was probably the middling classes – ranging from the rank and file of the urban craft guilds to the administrative professions and small merchants – who were crucial in the history of urban agriculture. Through their household and occupational model, they disposed of both access to land, from the backyard of their shop or house to a rented plot of land outside the city wall, and family labour, which was theoretically available to grow food. In present-day Central Europe (Poland and the Czech Republic) as well, middling groups have a much higher probability of engaging in home food gardening than labourers.46 It would hence be interesting to see if and how urban agriculture was impacted by the increasing social polarisation and the erosion of middling groups visible in many parts of Europe throughout the Early Modern period.47

And thirdly, the Early Modern professionalisation of horticulture was not a universal phenomenon. In the Low Countries, for instance, many cities did not display an inner von Thünen circle of specialised horticulture.48 In some cities professional guilds of gardeners (hoveniers or fruiteniers) existed, but as in the case of Antwerp, they might be more active in retailing vegetables and fruit rather than producing them themselves.49

So, while urban agriculture should certainly not be seen as limited to contexts of poverty or immature urban development, we should not a priori overestimate its historical importance either. We should keep in mind that a city of 10,000 inhabitants in 1600 needed about 90 square kilometres or 9,000 hectares to produce the bread grain it needed.50 Strictly localised food provisioning was thus out of the question. Even in a sparsely populated country such as Sweden, where cities were granted large swathes of agricultural land by the crown, urban food production seldom accounted for more than 30 percent of urban food consumption.51 There were notable exceptions, however, both in Sweden and elsewhere, and in many cases demography alone cannot explain why urban experiences with regard to urban agriculture were so divergent. At present, we remain largely ignorant of the importance of both home food gardens and professional or semi-professional horticulture for most parts of Europe throughout their history. Historians hence should urgently engage in mapping the contribution of urban and peri-urban agriculture (UPA) as well as other alternative urban food entitlements to the quality and quantity of urban food supply in different contexts.

Figure 1: Jan Wildens, Zicht op Antwerpen, 1636 (detail). Bird’s-eye view of Antwerp, with the gardening district south-east of the city at the bottom.

Illustration

Source: Amsterdam, Rijksmuseum, SK-A-616, https://www.rijksmuseum.nl/en/collection/SK-A-616.

Explaining the resilience and decline of urban agriculture

Confronted with a still very uncertain geography and chronology of urban food production, we can only formulate very modest suggestions on why urban agriculture boomed in one context but disappeared in others. Based on the available literature, a few questions and hypotheses can be formulated.

Access to land

From a supply-side perspective, historical variations in UPA might first of all be explained by access to land. Most forms of agriculture are land-based, and variations in access to land may strongly affect involvement in urban or peri-urban agricultural production. Access to land depends on the social distribution of land, which may have evolved in parallel to wealth inequalities, but also on institutional arrangements of landownership and land use, both within and beyond the city. In the urban hinterland, the rise of short-term leasehold or sharecropping provided a different potential for urban food production. In some cities, customary law was flexible enough to allow the fragmentation of property rights to urban real estate, which significantly increased the number of citizens owning parts of houses and gardens.5253